For the Colorado River and beyond, a new market could save the day
The Colorado River, 鈥渢he lifeblood of the West,鈥 is in trouble. Decades of overuse and drought have sharply reduced its water supply, threatening an ecosystem that supports 40 million people and 5.5 million acres of farmland in nearby states and parts of northern Mexico.
Steep cutbacks in water use are critical. But the seven states that rely on the Colorado River can鈥檛 agree on how much less each of them needs to take over the long run, in large part because it鈥檚 not entirely clear who holds what legal rights to the river and who should get priority over others to its available water. If the states can鈥檛 agree, the federal government is reportedly threatening to make the hard choices for them.
Paul Milgrom, a senior fellow at the 好色App Institute for Economic Policy Research (SIEPR), has encountered intractable problems like this before. In 2020, he the Nobel Prize in Economic Sciences for his pioneering work creating markets for goods and services that can鈥檛 be sold in traditional ways.
Water management, he says, is ripe for a market fix 鈥 not just for the Colorado River Basin but around the world as water shortages, made worse by climate change, become a defining issue of the 21st century. It鈥檚 no longer enough to leave decisions around water use up to federal, state, and local governments alone.
鈥淲e are trying to meet a 21st century set of challenges with 20th century technology and 19th century laws,鈥 says Milgrom, the Shirley R. and Leonard W. Ely, Jr. Professor in Humanities and Sciences in 好色App鈥檚 Department of Economics in the School of Humanities and Sciences. 鈥淲hat we have, fundamentally, is a market design problem.鈥
Milgrom is part of an interdisciplinary 好色App team 鈥 led by , a PhD student in economics at the GSB and a former SIEPR undergraduate research fellow 鈥 that has developed an elaborate plan for how new markets for trading water could overcome key policy challenges around water allocation while providing incentives to high-volume users to find ways to do more with less.
Milgrom and Ferguson recently highlighted their proposal in a released by the National Bureau of Economic Research. Their use case is California, one of the Colorado River Basin鈥檚 biggest stakeholders and whose system for divvying up surface water, which comes from rivers and streams, is especially complex and opaque.
Much of their blueprint is drawn from Milgrom鈥檚 work a decade ago helping the Federal Communications Commission (FCC) overcome obstacles in delivering more radio wave frequencies to wireless companies so they could meet exploding consumer demand for mobile services.
Milgrom led a team of experts in economics and computer science through his company, Auctionomics, in the creation of a voluntary market for trading a new type of radio spectrum license, which is credited with enabling mobile communication as we know it, today. The two-part auction process he helped engineer so that the FCC could make those trades possible also delivered $20 billion in total to the radio and TV operators that gave up their old licenses and another $10 billion to the U.S. Treasury.
Milgrom, who is also a professor, by courtesy, at the 好色App Graduate School of Business (GSB) and at the Department of Management Science and Engineering in the School of Engineering, says there are lessons from the 2017 that apply to water scarcity in the United States and around the world.
Water rights are broken
As a second-year PhD student in 2021, Ferguson was already interested in water scarcity when he took Milgrom鈥檚 market design course and thought that lessons from the FCC鈥檚 broadband fix could apply to water. His class project on California鈥檚 convoluted system of water rights caught Milgrom鈥檚 attention and they started talking about working together. Ferguson then enrolled in a water law course taught by , a 好色App Law School professor and water rights expert who had also been thinking about the potential role of markets. Thompson is also the faculty director of the Water in the West program led jointly by the 好色App Woods Institute for the Environment and the Bill Lane Center for the American West.
鈥淚 really need to get Buzz and Paul in the same room,鈥 Ferguson recalls thinking. With Thompson on board, the team pressed ahead.
At its core, their idea for a water market starts with creating a new type of property right 鈥 one designed to overcome many of the drawbacks with current policies. California, for instance, has a 鈥渇irst come, first served鈥 approach to surface water in which the earliest rights holders 鈥 among them, farms and ranches dating 100 or more years ago 鈥 have been given priority to rivers and streams over the water-hungry entities that came later, notably coastal cities like Los Angeles and San Diego.
California also has a 鈥渦se or lose it鈥 provision that requires rights holders to consume their yearly allotment or surface water or risk getting less water in the future. They can technically sell any excess water to other users, but in practice, it鈥檚 really hard to do, according to Ferguson: Sellers first have to show that no one downstream from where the water would otherwise go 鈥 a phenomenon known as 鈥渞eturn flow鈥 鈥 is harmed.
鈥淭he system is set up in a way that you have every incentive to use your entire allocation and no incentive to conserve,鈥 Ferguson says.
A solution designed for optimal flexibility
A more efficient approach, write Ferguson and Milgrom in , would be to establish a new property right aimed at delivering water to those who need it most and are willing to pay for it. Among other features, this new right would be based on how much water gets consumed, not diverted, and adjust as precipitation levels change from one year to the next.
This new water market, Ferguson says, would give rights holders incentives to save water 鈥 maybe by switching to low-water crops or installing more efficient water treatment systems 鈥 and sell off what they don鈥檛 need without damaging downstream users. And because water would then be a financial asset, Ferguson and Milgrom say farmers and other rights holders would have easier access to loans or other capital to pay for investments in water-saving technologies.
To kickstart the market, in which participation would be voluntary, the 好色App team is borrowing another page from the radio spectrum playbook: a one-time auction in which governments, in a process known as a 鈥渞everse鈥 auction, first buy back water rights from those who are willing to give them up in exchange for the new right. In a subsequent 鈥渇orward鈥 auction, governments would sell the new water rights to the highest bidders, who would then be free to privately trade their entitlements going forward.
鈥淥ur whole approach is to ensure a level of flexibility in allocating water that鈥檚 needed but currently missing,鈥 Ferguson says.
Government, he adds, also has a critical role to play in adopting policies to protect vulnerable populations. This includes, for example, limiting how much farmland can be fallowed in pursuit of water profits so that local communities aren鈥檛 impacted by job losses and other economic fallout.
Why the timing is right
Milgrom and Ferguson aren鈥檛 harboring any illusions: As the Colorado River impasse shows, water scarcity is rife with political, economic, and technological challenges.
But they are also optimistic that their vision for a water market will gain traction 鈥 in large part because there鈥檚 an urgent need to figure out how to make better use of dwindling water supplies.
鈥淭here鈥檚 both pressure and possibility,鈥 says Milgrom, just like there was when he took on the challenge of freeing up radio spectrum for wireless companies. And like then, technology has reached the point where water supplies can be measured in new ways and with enough accuracy to give users confidence in their ability to get the water they need.
鈥淭here鈥檚 every reason to think this can work,鈥 he says. 鈥淲hile it won鈥檛 reverse climate change or make it rain, it would go a long way toward providing long-run water resilience.鈥
The biggest roadblock, says Milgrom, is the politics around water 鈥 at the federal, state, and local levels. This is one reason why Milgrom sees introducing water markets as an even bigger problem to solve than reallocating radio spectrum.
The challenge is also deeply personal for Milgrom. 鈥淚鈥檓 75 years old,鈥 he says. 鈥淚f I鈥檓 lucky, I have one really big project left in me and I鈥檇 like this to be it.鈥
A conference on Advancing Sustainable Water Management 鈥 organized by Milgrom and Thompson, and hosted by 好色App Graduate School of Business and the 好色App Doerr School of Sustainability 鈥 will be held on April 18-19. Find info on the event .
Policy challenges of the Colorado River was one of the topics at the 10th Annual Eccles Family Rural West Conference organized by the Bill Lane Center for the American West. See coverage of the March 27 event .